<<Biblioteca Digital del Portal<<INTERAMER<<Serie Educativa<<Sustainable Development in Latin America: Financing and Policies Working in Synergy<<Environmental Enforcement in Latin America and the Caribbean
Colección: INTERAMER
Número: 69
Año: 2000
Autor: Ramón López and Juan Carlos Jordán, Editors
Título: Sustainable Development in Latin America: Financing and Policies Working in Synergy
Alternative Approaches to Enforcement: Private Enforcement
In order to circumvent some of the constraints faced by public enforcement
agencies, in particular resource and staff constraints, private enforcement
could be an alternative approach. Private enforcement can complement, or
even substitute for, public enforcement. Although many efforts at privatization
ultimately turn a public responsibility (such as fire protection) completely
over to the private sector, enforcement does not lend itself to that strategy.
In general, even in countries with strong private enforcement regimes,
public enforcers retain a prominent role. When authorizing private enforcement,
most legislatures have been cautious not to afford the private enforcers
too much power. Nevertheless, private enforcement is increasingly being
used to enforce environmental laws and regulations (Tietenberg, 1996).
Much like public enforcement, it can constitute a source of funds by earmarking
penalties for environmental purposes and, more indirectly, by making noncompliance
more expensive for polluters (Pearce, Ozdemiroglu, and Dobson, 1997).
Box 2
Private enforcement actions differ from more conventional liability actions
in that the initiator of the action is not primarily seeking to be compensated
for pollution-related damages (except in cases of civil liability actions),
but rather to bring a polluter into compliance or to force a public official
to carry out his or her legal responsibilities.
In Latin America and the Caribbean, the complaint is frequently triggered
by a perceived violation of a procedural requirement or of a fundamental
right to a clean environment that is not necessarily related to specific
legal discharge standards. Under the complaint form of private enforcement
the public authority may be designated as the recipient of any complaint
with full powers to investigate and dispose of it, as is the case in El
Salvador (Navarrete Lopez, 1994). In the United States and Europe the action
is more likely to be exclusively focused on a violation of a specific discharge
standard.
The right of citizens to participate directly in the enforcement of environmental
laws and regulations varies from one country to another. Unlike the United
States, most of the civil-law countries of the region do not have citizen
suit provisions in specific environmental laws.
Box 3
In most countries, citizen suits, if they exist, are generally derived
from the constitution or the civil codes. For instance, civil codes provide
citizens with the general right to bring legal action against any person
for failure to comply with the law (not specifically environmental laws).
In other countries, citizens’ rights are limited to complaint actions.
In Mexico, citizens have the right to complain to PROFEPA under the General
Law on Ecological Balance and Environmental Protection. El Salvador’s National
System of Environmental Complaints offers similar opportunities to its
citizens (Navarrete Lopez, 1994).
More recently, Mexico published a decree amending the law (December 13,
1996) that includes a right to demand review of government decisions and
file suit against environmental crimes (CEC, 1996). However, the provisions
have not been used so far, almost two years after the decree entered into
effect, which may reflect a certain lack of awareness in society about
available legal instruments (IER, 1998).
In Argentina, new clauses in the most recently amended National Constitution
have extended legal standing to people other than those directly affected
in their property or personal health. Private parties interested in community
goals of environmental quality are now able to file legal actions against
other private parties or the government (IDB, 1996).
The most liberal regime seems to exist in Brazil, where every citizen can
bring a claim before the courts, including for their environmental rights
granted by Article 225 of the Constitution. Concerned citizens may also
challenge administrative decisions that they consider not to be in accordance
with the law. Two proceedings are particularly important: (1) Popular Action
(Art. 5, LXXIII of the Federal Constitution) under which every citizen
has the right to challenge an administrative act because of alleged harm
to the environment (public wealth); and (2) Public Civil Actions (Art.
129, III of the Federal Constitution), under which the Public Ministry
and NGOs have legal standing.
It is said that the Brazilian Public Ministry is an institution unique
in Latin America. It operates completely independently of the government
and has evolved as the main plaintiff for environmental protection in Brazil.
In other countries, civil actions may also be brought by other actors,
such as an ombudsman (defensor del pueblo).
The Interaction of Public and Private Enforcement
Low levels of public enforcement might be expected to increase the private
benefits from private litigation activity. Violations could be expected
to be more frequent and more serious in periods of lax enforcement. It
follows that the optimal level of private enforcement is inversely related
to the amount of public enforcement. All other things being equal, we would
expect more citizen enforcement activity in countries with diminished government
enforcement activity. Similarly, within countries, we would expect more
private enforcement activity during periods of reduced public enforcement.
Box 4
However, private enforcement obviously also has potential disadvantages
to society. A public enforcement agency that has a clearly articulated
and effective strategy for allocating its resources to enforcement activities
could find its priorities completely subverted by private enforcement activity.
Responding to complaints and court challenges of its decisions consumes
time and resources. Some balance is needed to assure that legitimate, but
not excessive, pressure can be applied by private enforcers (Tietenberg,
1996). In his report, Tietenberg identifies two specific problems with
private enforcement: (1) its priorities in choosing which claims to pursue
will not necessarily coincide with social priorities; and (2) its actions
may not support the socially desirable intensity of control. This, however,
is not a fatal blow to private enforcement, according to Tietenberg. One
area where private enforcement may have the edge is in pursuing public
polluters and the other is corruption (see box 5).
Even though public facilities represent a substantial proportion of the
pollution problem, the enforcement of pollution-control laws presents special
problems for public enforcers in most countries. The evidence seems very
clear that public enforcement of violations by public polluters has been
quite ineffective, and that the problem is not the inadequate availability
of remedies, but rather the reluctance of public enforcers to use those
that exist (Gelpe, 1989).
Public and private enforcement can also complement each other. Private
enforcement, particularly citizen suits, can take on some of the routine
tasks, leaving the more serious problems to the public sector. Focusing
public enforcement activity on the most significant problems makes a great
deal of sense because of the ease of transferring information and expertise
from one case to another. If enforcement were the exclusive responsibility
of the public sector, however, focusing on priority areas could open the
possibility for polluters operating in non-targeted areas to exploit that
decision. They would respond to a perceived decline in public scrutiny
with reduced compliance. Since private enforcers are not operating on the
same set of priorities as public enforcers, the likelihood of private enforcement
in a non-targeted area is not diminished. With a continuing threat from
private enforcers, polluters have a continuing reason for compliance, even
when the public sector has its focus elsewhere. The very existence of the
private enforcement alternative allows public enforcers more flexibility
in targeting their resources, a flexibility that offers the opportunity
to use their limited resources more efficiently.
Box 5
The Sustainability of Private Enforcement Actions
By their very nature, completely successful private enforcers undermine
the reason for their existence. Once complete compliance has been obtained
no more opportunities for claims exist regardless of the underlying incentives.
Yet no private enforcement process currently in existence is presently
facing that prospect. The level of noncompliance is simply too great.
How, then, are private enforcers likely to sustain their contributions
to the enforcement process? The achievement of a sustainable process requires
a self-sustaining source of revenue in order to cover the costs of bringing
claims. The “loser pays” principle of allocating legal costs, which is
already part of the legal system in Latin America, provides a perfectly
reasonable vehicle for covering these costs. The reimbursement from each
previous successful action provides a fund to be used in pursuing the next
action. As long as the claims brought are meritorious, the fund keeps being
replenished.
It would be possible to carry this even further by authorizing that penalties
be paid directly to private enforcers rather than dedicated to environmental
improvement. In this case private enforcement would be a profitable activity
and bounty hunters could be expected to join. But while this high level
of incentive might well be merited in specific circumstances, its dangers
should be recognized. Bounty hunters certainly accelerate the movement
toward complete compliance. Whenever that may not be socially desirable,
this acceleration may prove to introduce significant problems. Since the
U.S. experience indicates that the reimbursement of attorneys’ fees may
be sufficient to make the process sustainable, it may not be necessary
to introduce bounty-hunter provisions.