<<Biblioteca Digital del Portal<<INTERAMER<<Serie Educativa<<Sustainable Development in Latin America: Financing and Policies Working in Synergy
Colección: INTERAMER
Número: 69
Año: 2000
Autor: Ramón López and Juan Carlos Jordán, Editors
Título: Sustainable Development in Latin America: Financing and Policies Working in Synergy
INTRODUCTION
Ramón López and Juan Carlos Jordán*
The financing of sustainable development has been a topic of great concern
since the Earth Summit held in Rio in 1992. At that meeting it was estimated
that over US$600 billion a year would be needed to implement Agenda 21
in the developing world. It was also understood that some US$125 billion
of this would come from grants and concessional loans from donor countries,
an amount that was roughly equivalent to 0.7% of their combined GNP.
In the ensuing years the share of official development assistance never
reached that Rio-commitment goal and in fact declined from 0.33% of GNP
in 1992 to about 0.24% by 1999. This trend was not unexpected, and has
heightened the importance of efforts to review and seek to enhance and
improve innovative international and domestic financing mechanisms. Within
the United Nations system, four expert-group meetings looking into this
matter have been held since 1994. The last one took place in Santiago,
Chile, in January of 1997, and its results were reported to the Special
Session of the United Nations General Assembly of 1997.1 At the Summit
of the Americas on Sustainable Development, held in Bolivia in December
of 1996, the countries of the Western Hemisphere expressed similar concerns
and asked the OAS, along with other institutions, to assist in the quest
for means of strengthening the financing of sustainable development.2
The present volume contains the papers presented at a technical meeting
held in October of 1998 by the General Secretariat of the OAS on policies,
problems, and financing of sustainable development in Latin America and
the Caribbean. It constitutes a contribution to the effort of finding new
ways of financing sustainable development in the region.
There has been a shift in how aid must be applied as the development process
becomes more market-driven and more participatory. As a result, much needs
to be done to restore donor support for aid. Greater overall transparency
will help to reduce conditions that are tied to it and avoid any possible
deviation from its intended use. Clear, sound, consistent economic, social,
and environmental policies will also ensure that aid recipients are making
a commitment to sustainable development that is worth supporting and ensure
that the concessional support they receive is not working at cross-purposes
or squandered.
Financial resources, while necessary for sustainable development, are not
sufficient to ensure that it is attained. Much more is needed. Developing
countries must put the right policies in place, seeking for each country
an appropriate balance of its economic, social, and environmental concerns
to ensure sustainability. The application of such policies will permit
better use of existing aid and also mobilize additional resources. It will
also guide consumers and producers toward more sustainable patterns of
behavior. In fact, proper policies will minimize environmental degradation
and thus hold down the costs of repair. They will also make complying with
environmental rules and regulations less costly.
An added benefit of sound policies is that they will enable countries to
attract and make better use of net foreign private capital flows, including
direct and portfolio investment. It has been argued that such flows should
play an increasing role in financing sustainable development. Foreign direct
investment (FDI), which provides risk capital that can contribute to growth,
poverty alleviation, improved skills, and environmentally friendly technologies,
has in fact increased considerably since the Earth Summit. In 1998 FDI
flows to developing countries were about US$155 billion, with about US$58
billion, or 37% of that, going to Latin America and the Caribbean. 3
This volume integrates different aspects of the policies, programs, and
financing for sustainable development. The main conclusions can be summarized
into three broad categories: (1) the promotion and financing of better
monitoring of certain key environmental resources and ways to improve the
enforcement of existing environmental laws and regulations; (2) global
externalities and the potential of trade in carbon-emission rights as a
mechanism to enhance biodiversity conservation and forest protection and
raise financial resources for sustainability; and (3) market-based instruments
(MBI) versus command-and-control mechanisms (CAC) as instruments to control
pollution and mobilize financial resources for sustainability.
The monitoring of environmental resources is a precondition for any program
of environmental sustainability and is an area where international cooperation
is essential. The establishment of systems of environmental information
could also facilitate capacity building by promoting technical cooperation
and expertise among environmental officers in the public and private sectors.
Additionally, the issue of enforcement is critical in the region. Most
problems of environmental waste are due not so much to lack of environmental
laws, which in many cases are extraordinarily comprehensive, as to insufficient
enforcement and to the design of the legislation that sometimes makes it
difficult to enforce. Further, more efficient monitoring systems and the
enforcement of environmental laws would generate additional savings by
reducing the costs of repairing damage done to the environment.
Among the key topics considered within the broad category of “monitoring
and enforcement” are those issues related to institutional reform and build-up,
private enforcement, and environmental fines and their earmarking for environmental
institutions. One special related issue concerns the problem of enforcing
environmental regulations on public agents.
The existence of global externalities (related to greenhouse gases and
biodiversity) can potentially be a source of opportunities to enhance trade
in environmental services (most notably in natural forest and biodiversity
conservation) between the region and the developed countries. Large volumes
of financial resources that can be used to finance many initiatives can
be raised through this mechanism. This opportunity is greatly enhanced
by the recent Kyoto meeting.
The specific conclusions that emerge from the studies in these areas are
the following:
Monitoring, Enforcement, and Institutions
A necessary condition for proper environmental enforcement is the development
of adequate environmental institutions. The underdevelopment of private
environmental institutions (property rights, markets, etc.) seems to be
related more to endogenous factors associated with lack of economic incentives
for their establishment than to exogenous factors. Hence, it seems indispensable
to explore policies that can increase the economic incentives for the development
of institutions in the private and public sectors.
The development of public environmental institutions is another essential
condition for adequate environmental monitoring and enforcement. Earmarking,
in particular of fines and charges for public services, is potentially
valuable, not only as a mechanism to provide automatic financing for public
agencies in charge of environmental enforcement, but also as an incentive
for institutional build-up among such agencies. Environmental agencies
could use part of their earmarked revenues to improve their human and physical
capabilities to do their work.
Partly because of a lack of full understanding of environmental effects
and partly because of lack of enforcement capacity of the officials in
charge of the environment, public polluters act with relative impunity
throughout the region; in some cases they constitute the principal source
of pollution. For instance, the experience in the Cauca Valley in Colombia
shows that, although the mechanisms in place were successful in controlling
pollution from private agents, the overall environmental gains were undermined
by the lack of compliance on the part of the local public utilities. It
is essential to consider these public polluters in the design of appropriate
environmental regulations, and especially with regard to mechanisms that
involve private participation in the enforcement of the regulations.
An interesting issue emphasized in the papers is the necessity of establishing
environmental legislation and regulations that are both realistic and feasible
to enforce, as opposed to the old laws that tended to set excessively ambitious
standards and thus were extremely difficult to implement.
Environmental fines not only play a substantial role as methods for raising
revenues but, more importantly, represent important compliance mechanisms.
They might be a good way to raise revenues for environmental mitigation
from polluters themselves. This could considerably increase the fairness
of these programs and thus increase their public support.
International Trade in Global Environmental Services
The region has enormous financial needs for sustainable development. Local
sources are unlikely to be sufficient to cover even a relatively small
fraction of these needs. Traditional international aid for the environment
has not been in the past a significant source of funding, and it is likely
to shrink even more in the future. An important, yet unexplored, option
is to obtain such funding through international trade in global goods,
particularly in climate services provided by the region’s large remaining
tropical forest.
It is shown that the region could obtain large net financial revenues by
participating in world trade in carbon emissions, provided that the North
explicitly recognizes deforestation as a source of carbon emission. In
this scenario, the region could sell part of its deforestation rights and
obtain huge financial revenues without compromising its future economic
growth. Additionally, those revenues should dramatically increase the value
of standing forests, thus providing incentives for the establishment of
effective property-rights institutions in forested areas. The region should
therefore become fully involved in the global efforts to reduce carbon
emissions by trading permits, developing a set of specific conditions required
for such participation.
MBIs versus CACs
To avoid the risks of spreading the regulatory efforts too thin among a
variety of MBIs and CACs, there is a need to establish priorities on the specific
areas in which each would be applied. Although MBIs are not a panacea, these
mechanisms are potentially attractive in the sense that they may be more efficient
than CACs under certain conditions, or can complement CACs. However, the papers
identify instances where CAC instruments should continue to be used. It seems
that, while some progress has been attained in the management and control of
point sources of water pollution using CACs and sometimes MBIs, there is a significant
imbalance with respect to non-point sources. It may be important to explore
inexpensive ways of tackling some of these as well.
NOTES
1. United Nations, Finance for Sustainable Development: The Road Ahead,
New York, 1997.
2. See Declaration of Santa Cruz de la Sierra and Plan of Action for the
Sustainable Development of the Americas.
3. World Bank, Global Development Finance 1999, Chapter 3, Washington D.C.,
1999