<<Biblioteca Digital del Portal<<INTERAMER<<Serie Educativa<<Sustainable Development in Latin America: Financing and Policies Working in Synergy<<Why Latin America Should Participate in Global Trade in Carbon Emissions: Carbon Trade as a Source of Funding for Sustainable Development
Colección: INTERAMER
Número: 69
Año: 2000
Autor: Ramón López and Juan Carlos Jordán, Editors
Título: Sustainable Development in Latin America: Financing and Policies Working in Synergy
Flow of Resources in a Carbon Trade Scenario: A Regional Overview
As can be seen in Table 3, if only industrial emissions are considered,
Latin America’s share of global CO2 emissions is only 4.5% of the total
world emissions. But if all sources are considered, including deforestation,
the region’s share almost doubles to 9%. The 640 million metric tons of
CO2 are generated by deforestation of about 5.7 million ha in South America
and 0.7 million ha in Central America.
The assumption made in estimating the CO2 emissions from deforestation
assumes an average release per ha of 100 tons of CO2. This figure is quite
conservative given the few available analyses of carbon sequestration in
tropical forests. A recent survey by the WRI (1998) shows that the CO2
content of tropical forests around the world ranges between 188 and 348
tons per ha. Thus, using the lowest estimate and assuming that only 54%
of the total CO2 is actually released into the atmosphere through forest
conversion we obtain an estimate of 100 tons of CO2 per ha.
What would be the market value of the forest area that is eliminated every
year in Latin America? A recent study has found that the likely price of
the right to emit one ton of CO2 would be $125 if carbon trade were restricted
to the North (Ellerman, Jacoby, and Decaux, 1998). If the South is also
fully involved in the trading system, the quota price falls to $25 per
ton. Using the most pessimistic prediction for the quota value, we obtain
a market value of about $16 billion for the 6.4 million ha of forest annually
converted. This compares to less than $500 million in annual benefits to
the region of the 6.4 million ha that are converted to other purposes (López,
1998). Thus, the value of the standing forests of Latin America can be
dramatically increased if the region becomes fully involved in the imminent
world carbon-trade system. At the same time, the region can obtain large
financial benefits that could be devoted to sustainable development and
the fight against poverty.
What are the potential drawbacks to the region of integrating itself into
the world carbon trade? The region would have to accept binding aggregate
CO2 quotas. There is a fear that this could restrict its future development
potential. The issue here is how the CO2 quota for the region is set up.
A historical benchmark is inevitable, but the region could set as a condition
that the volume of quotas received should be adjustable through time so
that per capita CO2 emission rights would gradually converge with those
of the North. This could imply, for example, a North-South annual redistribution
of CO2 quotas of the order of, say, 0.5% per annum. More importantly, the
region has property rights over its entire forest resources. Therefore,
Latin America should have the right to continue deforestation at its present
level until its forests are depleted. Thus, the region would reduce deforestation
below the historical 6.4 million ha in return for the corresponding quota
values. That is, the region would have for the foreseeable future the right
to emit 640 million tons of CO2 per annum and could sell such rights every
year at the quota market price. Of course, deforestation in the future
cannot affect the areas that have been “sold” for carbon-sequestration
purposes. As domestic industrial development demands greater CO2 emission
rights, the region could export a smaller fraction of its deforestation
quotas and use the rest domestically.
Figure 2 shows the likely evolution of the CO2 emissions for the region
assuming that it reduces deforestation by 50% in perpetuity, that is, that
it cuts its deforestation from 6.4 to 3.2 million ha per annum. It is also
assumed that the region’s GDP grows at 5% per annum and that the elasticity
of demand for CO2 with respect to GDP is 0.40. This implies that the demand
for CO2 emissions for industrial development would increase 2% per annum.
Figure 2 shows that by reallocating its deforestation quota gradually from
foreign to domestic sectors, the region can continue to grow at 5% for
over 28 years without facing CO2 constraints. Throughout this period the
region would have gross revenues related to the deforestation quotas of
about US$62 billion expressed in present value using a 10% discount rate
(Table 4). Over the first few years, the quota revenues would reach US$8
billion annually. The cost of reducing deforestation by 50% in terms of
forgone revenues from the land that is not developed would amount to less
than US$4.8 billion, also in terms of present value. That is, the region
is likely to obtain a net benefit of more than US$60 billion over the next
28 years without facing binding restrictions on its growth rate. Of course,
if the GDP growth rate turned out to be higher, the net quota revenues
would decline.
What happens when the deforestation quotas are fully used? The region could
negotiate further reallocation of emission rights from the North from time
to time until per capita emissions in the region are close enough to those
of the North. Additionally, in the future it may become easier to reduce
deforestation even further, to below 3.2 million ha per annum. This would
give the region more quota benefits and, at the same time, allow it to
reach levels of emissions per capita much closer to those of the North.
Another issue concerns implementation: how to achieve the target of cutting
deforestation significantly and how to distribute the benefits of the quota
revenues to facilitate achieving the reductions in deforestation. These will
be dealt with in section 6.
FIGURE 2
TABLE 4
FIGURE 2
TABLE 4